Related Books

An Encyclopedia of Keynesian Economics, Second edition
Edited by Thomas Cate, Northern Kentucky University, US

Teaching Post Keynesian Economics
Edited by Jesper Jespersen, Roskilde University, Denmark and Mogens Ove Madsen, Aalborg University, Denmar

Monetary Economies of Production
Edited by Louis-Philippe Rochon, Laurentian University, Canada and Co-editor, Review of Keynesian Economics and Mario Seccareccia, University of Ottawa, Canada

Review of Keynesian Economics
About this Journal

The Review of Keynesian Economics (ROKE) is dedicated to the promotion of research in Keynesian economics. Not only does that include Keynesian ideas about macroeconomic theory and policy, it also extends to microeconomic and meso-economic analysis and relevant empirical and historical research. The journal provides a forum for developing and disseminating Keynesian ideas, and intends to encourage critical exchange with other macroeconomic paradigms.

Aims and scope

It is widely recognized that economic crises can sometimes trigger enormous change, both with regard to economic theory and the politics of governance. Today, the global economy is struggling with the fall-out from the financial crash of 2008 and the Great Recession of 2007-09. The economic crisis that these events have generated, combined with the failure of the mainstream economics profession, has again put the question of change on the table.

With regard to the economics profession, it stands significantly discredited owing to its failure to foresee the recession and the financial crash; its repeated over-optimistic forecasts of rapid recovery; and lack of plausibility surrounding its attempts to explain events. Reasonable people do not expect economists to predict the daily movements of the stock market, but they do expect them to anticipate and explain major imminent economic developments. On that score the profession failed catastrophically, revealing fundamental theoretical inadequacies.

This intellectual failure has prompted us to launch the Review of Keynesian Economics. At a time of journal proliferation some may wonder about the need for another journal. We would respond there is a proliferation of journals but that proliferation is essentially within one intellectual paradigm. As such, it obscures the fact that the range of theoretical inquiry is actually very narrow. A journal devoted to Keynesian economics is therefore needed both to correct this narrowness and because events have once again confirmed the profound relevance of Keynesian theory.

Reflection upon the intellectual history of macroeconomics over the past seventy-five years can help to understand the current predicament and need for this new journal. That history traces an arc, which first saw the eclipse of classical macroeconomics by Keynesian macroeconomics, and then saw the eclipse of Keynesian macroeconomics by a revived and re-tooled classical macroeconomics.

The crisis associated with the Great Depression of the 1930s inspired John Maynard Keynes to write The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money, a book that explained the persistence of unemployment in monetary economies. Keynes' theory had enormous influence both inside and outside the academy, and his ideas on the importance of effective demand triggered a remaking of macroeconomics that saw Keynesian theory displace classical macroeconomic theory. That displacement was driven by the failure of classical theory to account for the Depression and the corresponding explanatory success of Keynesian theory. Moreover, not only did Keynesian theory provide an explanatory framework, it also offered practical policy recommendations. After World War II, the Keynesian theoretical revolution inspired new policy thinking that contributed to a twenty-five year period of unprecedented prosperity, now widely referred to as “The Golden Age” of capitalism or “The Age of Keynes”.

From 1945 to the early 1970s, the global economy witnessed an unparalleled period of prosperity that came to an end with the collapse of Bretton Woods (1971), the first oil crisis (1973) and the stock market crash of 1973-74. During this period of almost three decades, the world enjoyed rapid growth, low unemployment and reduced inequality, making Keynesian policies a success by most measures.

However, adherents of classical macroeconomic theory never accepted the legitimacy of Keynesian economics and they forged a counter-revolution, centered upon the University of Chicago and the work of Milton Friedman. In the 1960s and early 1970s the counter-revolution took the form of monetarism, and thereafter it evolved into new classical macroeconomics. The intellectual link between monetarism and new classical macroeconomics was animosity to Keynesianism and a dogmatic predisposition to laissez-faire conclusions.

The counter-revolutionaries were successful in their project and recaptured control of macroeconomics in the late 1970s. Their success was driven by a range of factors including their own intellectual imagination and innovation, intellectual staleness among Keynesians; the Cold War, which promoted laissez-faire ideology; and inflation and political conflict triggered by income distribution conflicts fostered first by full employment and then by the oil shocks of the 1970s.

Most importantly, the counter-revolutionaries opportunistically exploited the intellectual confusions created by the oil supply shocks of the early 1970s. Those shocks unleashed a new supply-side phenomenon of stagflation, which the counter-revolutionaries asserted disproved Keynesian macroeconomics. In retrospect, we know those assertions were false and Keynesian theories of conflict inflation gave a good account of developments, but the dispiritedness of the late 1970s initiated an era of reaction, which included reaction in economics.

It is important to emphasize that the demise of Keynesian economics was not caused by profound logical flaws or lack of supportive empirical evidence. Keynesianism (and other paradigms too) was accused of lacking micro-foundations, when in reality it has always had micro-foundations but rejects micro-foundations predicated on the implausible assumptions of homo economicus and Walrasian characterization of market processes. That Walrasian characterization fundamentally misrepresents economic reality, assuming the existence of institutions that do not exist (i.e. the auctioneer) and ignoring institutions that do exist (i.e. money and money contracting). In doing so, it ignores the macro-foundations that for Keynesians are the twin of micro-foundations.

The inflationary pressures of the 1970s, with the concomitant rise of conservatism in the form of the Reagan-Thatcher movements, were instrumental in the revival of classical macroeconomics and the repression of Keynesian economics. These forces have now waned but they have locked-in a legacy that is hard to reverse. That is because notions such as the natural rate of unemployment are entrenched in macroeconomics discussions and, most importantly, in teaching manuals.

The consequences of the return of classical macroeconomics have been enormous. For society it has entailed an era of neoliberal policy dominance that has contributed to wage stagnation and massive income inequality, which is significantly responsible for the Great Recession and the prospect of stagnation. Economic theory and politics often march hand-in-hand, with theory reinforcing politics and politics reinforcing theory. Together, they both drive policy, making economic theory vitally important for society.

In the end, economic theory is a contested terrain that is fought over by different intellectual tendencies, which may reflect different political and ethical values. In the years after World War II Keynesianism was ascendant, but since the late 1970s classical macroeconomics has been ascendant. Such ebbs and flows are reasonable, and even desirable, in an open society. However, what troubles us is that the period of classical re-ascendance has been characterized by what we think is a closing and monopolization of intellectual space, whereas the period of Keynesian ascendancy was marked by intellectual pluralism.

This closing of economics is significantly attributable to the laissez-faire ideological predispositions of new classical macroeconomics. It has also has been driven by economists' disdain for epistemological concerns, which has fostered intellectual intolerance and over-reach. Competing theoretical paradigms have been framed inappropriately in terms of truth versus error, a frame that inevitably drives exclusion of the paradigm labeled as being in error. This framing is supported by an erroneous belief that science produces a single true answer. Much vaunted mathematical rigor is built on conceptual narrowness and sloppiness, and the use of math is as much a rhetorical device for selective screening of ideas as it is for exploring the logical coherence of ideas.

These flawed practices have distorted the academy, and in doing so have had profoundly negative consequences for society. That concerns us in our dual identities as professional economists and citizens, and it is this concern that motivates the founding of the journal.

As the name signals, the journal promotes research in a particular paradigm -- the Keynesian paradigm. We make no apologies for this. Journals on international economics promote research in international economics: journals on finance promote research in financial economics. We have no objection to journals promoting particular types of economic research or thinking. What we object to is general-purpose and field journals only permitting research in a particular paradigm.

This journal is about Keynesian economics – without any qualifying adjective or prefix. Our aim is to encourage research and discourse in Keynesian economics – be it old Keynesianism, fundamental Keynesianism, neo-Keynesianism, Post Keynesianism, Sraffian Keynesianism, Kaleckian Keynesianism, or Marxist Keynesianism. The journal is open to all forms of Keynesianism, which we define as (1) holding that output and employment are normally constrained by aggregate demand, (2) holding that the problematic of aggregate demand shortage exists independently of price, nominal wage, and nominal interest rate rigidities, and (3) rejecting the claim that the real wage is equal to the marginal disutility of labor.

This openness to all forms of Keynesianism reflects a desire to avoid intellectual sectarianism, which we think has afflicted past Keynesian discourse. In our view, circumstance and ability certainly contributed to the success of the classical macroeconomics counter-revolutionaries, but so too did intellectual and sociological failure among Keynesians. Their tendency to apply arbitrary litmus tests and engage in intellectual sectarianism did a disservice to their project, and in doing so did disservice to society. We want to avoid repeating that history.

The contract with the journal publisher, Edward Elgar, was signed in 2011. We, the founding editors, are very happy with this timing as 2011 marked the seventy-fifth anniversary of Keynes' General Theory. The founding of the Review of Keynesian Economics is a fitting tribute and celebration of this anniversary. It is also part of the deeper response needed to meet these challenging economic times.

The journal is dedicated to the development of Keynesian theory and policy. In our view, Keynesian theory should hold a similar place in economics to that held by the theory of evolution in biology. Many individual economists still work within the Keynesian paradigm, but intellectual success demands institutional support that can leverage those individual efforts. The journal offers such support by providing a forum for developing and sharing Keynesian ideas. Not only does that include ideas about macroeconomic theory and policy, it also extends to microeconomic and meso-economic analysis and relevant empirical and historical research. We see a bright future for the Keynesian approach to macroeconomics and invite the economics profession to join us by subscribing to the journal and submitting manuscripts.

Editorial Information

Co-Editors

  • Thomas Palley
  • Associate of the New America Foundation's economic growth program. He was formerly Chief Economist of the US-China Economic and Security Review Commission. Prior to joining the Commission he was Director of the Open Society Institute's Globalization Reform Project, and before that he was Assistant Director of Public Policy at the AFL-CIO
  • Louis-Philippe Rochon
  • Associate Professor of Economics and Director of the International Economic Policy Institute, Laurentian University, Canada
  • Matias Vernengo
  • Associate Professor, Bucknell University, US

Associate Editors

  • Corrado Di Guilmi
  • Economics Discipline Group, University of Technology, Sydney, Australia
  • Jamee Moudud
  • Economics Faculty, Sarah Lawrence College, US
  • Codrina Rada
  • Assistant Professor, Economics Department, University of Utah, US

Board of Patrons

  • Yilmaz Akyüz, Switzerland
  • José Antonio Ocampo, USA
  • Amit Bhaduri, India
  • Robert Boyer, France
  • Luiz Carlos Bresser-Pereira, Brazil
  • William Darity Jr, USA
  • Jane D'Arista, USA
  • Heiner Flassbeck, Switzerland
  • Roberto Frenkel, Argentina
  • Charles A.E. Goodhart, UK
  • Stephanie Griffith-Jones, USA
  • Gustav Horn, Germany
  • Jomo K.S., USA
  • John E. King, Australia
  • Julio López Gallardo, Mexico
  • Arturo O'Connell, Argentina
  • Alain Parguez, France
  • Bob Rowthorn, UK
  • Robert Skidelsky, UK
  • John Smithin, Canada
  • Robert M. Solow, Nobel Laureate in Economics 1987, USA
  • Lance Taylor, USA
  • Anthony P. Thirlwall, UK

Editorial Board

  • Martín Abeles, Economic Commission for Latin America and the Carribean, Argentina
  • Angel Asensio, Université Paris 13, France
  • Robert Blecker, American University, USA
  • Hassan Bougrine, Laurentian University, Canada
  • Alcino Ferreira Camara Neto, Federal University of Rio de Janeiro, Brazil
  • Eugenia Correa, Universidad Nacional Autonoma de Mexico
  • Robert Dimand, Brock University, Canada
  • Peter Docherty, University of Technology, Sydney, Australia
  • Sebastian Dullien, HTW Berlin - University of Applied Sciences, Germany
  • Amitava Krishna Dutt, University of Notre Dame, USA
  • Gary Dymski, Leeds University Business School, UK
  • Steve Fazzari, Washington University in St Louis, USA
  • Claude Gnos, Université de Bourgogne, Dijon, France
  • Eckhard Hein, Berlin School of Economics and Law, Germany
  • Marc Lavoie, University of Ottawa, Canada
  • Maria Cristina Marcuzzo, University of Rome, Italy
  • Wesley Marshall, Universidad Autonoma Metropolitana, Mexico
  • Man-seop Park, Korea University, South Korea
  • Esteban Pérez Caldentey, Economic Commission for Latin American and the Caribbean, Chile
  • Ignacio Perrotini Hernández, Universidad Nacional Autonoma de Mexico, Mexico
  • Pascal Petit, CEPN Centre économie de Paris Nord, France
  • Robert Pollin, University of Massachusetts, Amherst, USA
  • Jean-Francois Ponsot, Universite de Grenoble, France
  • Jaime Ros, University of Notre Dame, USA
  • Sergio Rossi, University of Fribourg, Switzerland
  • Malcolm Sawyer, University of Leeds, UK
  • Stephanie Seguino, University of Vermont, USA
  • Franklin Serrano, Federal University of Rio de Janeiro, Brazil
  • Mark Setterfield, Trinity College, Hartford, USA
  • Takashi Yagi, Meiji University, Japan
  • Nobuharu Yokokawa, Musashi University, Japan
Subscriptions

ISSN Print 2049-5323
ISSN Online 2049-5331

Individuals: £107/$174 (online and print); £70/$114 (online only)
Institutions:£303/$488 (online and print); £265/$428 (online only)
Single print issue: £65/$100
Students: £52.50/$84 (online only)

50% discount for new subscribers when taking out a subscription to all five journals
30% discount for new subscribers when taking out a subscription to both EJEEP and ROKE

To place a subscription (worldwide):-

The Subscriptions Dept
Marston Book Services Ltd
160 Eastern Avenue, Milton Park, Abingdon
OXON OX14 4SB UK
Tel: 44 1235 465574 • Fax: 44 1235 465556
Email: subscriptions@marston.co.uk

Developing Countries Access

Edward Elgar offers free online access to the world's least developed countries. Access is offered to established not-for-profit educational institutions in the countries listed on the World Bank's least developed countries index. Interested parties are required to fill in the below form and either email to: journals@e-elgar.co.uk or fax the form to Emily Milsom =44 1242 262111.

Developing Countries Access Application Form

Author Submissions

Call for Papers and Author Guidelines

ROKE adheres to a double-blind review process. The editors are looking for research-quality papers on a wide variety of topics in economics and political-economy. Articles should be sent by email, and should not be more than 8,000 words, including references and bibliography.

Submissions and editorial queries should be sent to the Co-Editor: Louis-Philippe Rochon (lprochon2003@yahoo.com). Book reviews should be sent to Virginie Monvoisin, Grenoble Ecole de Management, France (virginie.monvoisin@grenoble-em.com)

Style/Submissions Guide

Article manuscripts should be prepared in accordance with our house style guidelines ROKE Guidance

The final version of your article should be accompanied by a completed copy of the Author Information Form
ROKE Information Form

Terms of publication

If your article is accepted for publication, you will be asked to sign our standard Contributor Agreement
ROKE Contributor Agreement

General Information

Table of contents alerts

To receive TOC alerts, please sign up above ‘Add TOC Alert’
Alternatively email: journals@e-elgar.co.uk

Information for librarians

In the absence of a separate license agreement, Edward Elgar Publishing follows the SERU guidelines for subscriptions to the Review of Keynesian Economics, as published at the NISO SERU website: http://www.niso.org/committees/SERU/.

Edward Elgar is also able to enter in to a signed license agreement with institutions if this is preferred. Two copies must be signed and sent to: Edward Elgar Publishing Ltd, The Lypiatts, 15 Lansdown Road, Cheltenham, GL50 2JA, UK, email: journals@e-elgar.co.uk with any queries. Or go to our license page.

Rights and Permissions

Please direct any requests to Jennie Hawdon, email: jennie@e-elgar.co.uk

Download a flyer

ROKE Journal Flyer

Useful links

http://rokeonline.com

Download our Journals Ethics Policy

ROKE Publication Ethics and Malpractice Statement

Open Access in Elgar Journals

All Elgar Journals give to authors the option of making their article Open Access via the Gold Open Access route, under the following criteria:

  • Requests will only be considered after the article has been submitted, peer-reviewed and accepted for publication by the Journal.
  • An author processing charge of £1000 per article is applicable.
  • The Article will be made publicly available on Elgaronline under a Creative Commons license (CC-BY-NC), both in free-flowing HTML and as a PDF download.
  • The version of the Article made available on Elgaronline will be the final published version of the full Article, both in free-flowing HTML and as a PDF download.
  • Authors can embed a link into any public repository or web-page which links directly to the final version of the full article on Elgaronline.

Download our Self Archiving Policy document

Self Archiving Policy

Abstracting and Indexing

  • Business Source Complete, EBSCO
  • EconLit, American Economics Association
  • RePEc

Discovery Services

  • Exlibris
  • Summon
  • OCLC
  • EBSCO Discovery
  • Google Scholar
  • CrossRef

Digital Preservation Services

  • Portico