The Nature of Economic Growth

The Nature of Economic Growth

An Alternative Framework for Understanding the Performance of Nations

A. P. Thirlwall

This concise book, by one of the leading scholars in development economics, has been developed from a series of lectures given to masters students and will serve as an excellent introduction to the principles of growth and development theory.

Chapter 2: Neoclassical and ‘New’ Growth Theory: A Critique

A. P. Thirlwall

Subjects: development studies, development economics, economics and finance, development economics, post-keynesian economics


Our task in this chapter is to outline formally the assumptions and predictions of neoclassical growth theory as a background to showing, firstly, how the neoclassical production function is used for analysing growth rate differences between countries, and its weaknesses; and secondly, how neoclassical growth theory forms the basis for ‘new’ endogenous growth theory – the only major difference being that the assumption of diminishing returns to capital is relaxed, so that ‘new’ growth theory is subject to the same major criticisms as conventional neoclassical theory as far as analysing and understanding growth rate differences between countries is concerned. The Neoclassical Model The neoclassical growth model is based on three key assumptions. The first is that the labour force (l) and labour-saving technical progress (t) grow at a constant exogenous rate. The second assumption is that all saving is invested: S = I = sY. There is no independent investment function. The third 20 Thirlwall 02 chaps rprnt 20 28/6/07 15:02:00 Neoclassical and ‘new’ growth theory: a critique 21 assumption is that output is a function of capital and labour, where the production function exhibits constant returns to scale, and diminishing returns to individual factors of production. The most commonly used neoclassical production function, with constant returns to scale, is the so-called Cobb–Douglas production function, named after Charles Cobb, a mathematician, and Paul Douglas, a well-known Chicago economist before World War II (who later became a US senator). The function takes the form: Y = TKαL1–α, (2.1) where Y is...

You are not authenticated to view the full text of this chapter or article.

Elgaronline requires a subscription or purchase to access the full text of books or journals. Please login through your library system or with your personal username and password on the homepage.

Non-subscribers can freely search the site, view abstracts/ extracts and download selected front matter and introductory chapters for personal use.

Your library may not have purchased all subject areas. If you are authenticated and think you should have access to this title, please contact your librarian.

Further information