Macroeconomics of Growth Cycles and Financial Instability

Macroeconomics of Growth Cycles and Financial Instability

New Directions in Modern Economics series

Piero Ferri

In light of the recent economic crisis and in keeping with Hyman Minsky’s analysis of financial instability, this book considers the important interaction between cycles and growth, via the interplay between demand, supply and real-world financial issues.

Chapter 9: Uncertainty, Expectations and Learning

Piero Ferri

Subjects: economics and finance, post-keynesian economics

Extract

1. THE ROLE OF EXPECTATIONS In the previous chapter, we have referred to the perfect foresight hypothesis. In other words, we made the hypothesis that there is a coincidence between expectations and reality. This hypothesis is undoubtedly strong and it can be useful as a benchmark. For instance, its results can be contrasted with those derived from the adaptive expectations hypothesis, which was the most widespread formula used until the years of the first oil shocks, also named the stagflation period. As has been stressed in Part I, there is a strong interdependence between facts and theory. In the 1970s, the hypothesis of adaptive expectations was considered untenable for at least two reasons. Firstly, it seemed to contrast with the facts. Secondly, it seemed to conflict with the rationality of the agent. These new questions brought about three important changes in macroeconomics. Firstly, any macro equation has to be microfounded. Secondly, expectations must be rational. Finally, supply-side policies have become predominant. In this context, the Phillips curve (see Ferri, 2000), which seems to be compatible with demand policy, is severely questioned. Not only is its shape under rigorous scrutiny, but its mere existence is under attack (see also Sargent, 1999). 2. ADAPTIVE EXPECTATIONS In the literature, expectations have mainly referred to prices and inflation. To this purpose, the scheme by Friedman and Cagan (see Sargent, 1999, p.51) is particularly revealing: xt 2 xt21 5 (1 2 l) [ yt21 2 xt21 ] , (9.1) where l lies between 0 and 1. If one...

You are not authenticated to view the full text of this chapter or article.

Elgaronline requires a subscription or purchase to access the full text of books or journals. Please login through your library system or with your personal username and password on the homepage.

Non-subscribers can freely search the site, view abstracts/ extracts and download selected front matter and introductory chapters for personal use.

Your library may not have purchased all subject areas. If you are authenticated and think you should have access to this title, please contact your librarian.

Further information