Handbook of Game Theory and Industrial Organization, Volume II
Show Less

Handbook of Game Theory and Industrial Organization, Volume II

Applications

Edited by Luis C. Corchón and Marco A. Marini

This second volume of the Handbook includes original contribution by experts in the field. It provides up-to-date surveys of the most relevant applications of game theory to industrial organization. The book covers both classical as well as new IO topics such as mergers in markets with homogeneous and differentiated goods, leniency and coordinated effects in cartels and mergers, static and dynamic contests, consumer search and product safety, strategic delegation, platforms and network effects, auctions, environmental and resource economics, intellectual property, healthcare, corruption, experimental industrial organization and empirical models of R & D.
Buy Book in Print
Show Summary Details
You do not have access to this content

Chapter 2: Horizontal mergers in oligopoly

Applications

Ramon Faulí‐Oller and Joel Sandonis

Extract

Mergers are a very important empirical phenomenon and form an important part of firms’ strategies: we see daily merger announcements in the business press. There can be several different motives for mergers. Apart from an attempt to gain market shares and market power, mergers can seek efficiency gains through the combination of different assets, or by getting access to new technologies and know-how; they can also seek to reach new groups of consumers or new geographical markets, showing a desire for diversification; in other cases, mergers can also seek to safeguard access to important inputs. When studying mergers, we have to be cautious because there are different types of mergers that require different theoretical treatments. The first distinction is between conglomerate, horizontal and vertical mergers. In this chapter, we focus on horizontal mergers, that is, mergers between firms that are direct competitors. Conglomerate mergers are mergers that take place between firms operating in unrelated markets, whereas vertical mergers occur between firms operating at successive stages of the production process. Horizontal mergers reduce competition. Mergers whose only aim is to reduce competition (or to gain market power) create the following free-riding problem. The reduction of competition due to a merger works as a public good that benefits all the firms in the industry, while the costs are only supported by the merging parties. This implies that non-merging firms benefit more from the merger than merging firms. Therefore, firms want competitors to merge. This result does not depend on the type of competition being either Bertrand or Cournot, however, the problem is more acute in a Cournot setting, where mergers may turn out to be unprofitable, i.e. the joint profits of the merging firms before the merger are higher than their joint profits after the merger. The explanation is the aggressive response of outsiders, which react to the output reduction by the merging firms by increasing their own output (quantities are strategic substitutes). This point was first raised by Salant, Switzer and Reynolds (1983). This response is so unexpected that it is usually known as the “merger paradox”. It originated a huge literature that tried to obtain profitable mergers in a Cournot setting. For example, profitability of mergers increases if either demand or costs become more convex.

You are not authenticated to view the full text of this chapter or article.

Elgaronline requires a subscription or purchase to access the full text of books or journals. Please login through your library system or with your personal username and password on the homepage.

Non-subscribers can freely search the site, view abstracts/ extracts and download selected front matter and introductory chapters for personal use.

Your library may not have purchased all subject areas. If you are authenticated and think you should have access to this title, please contact your librarian.


Further information

or login to access all content.